News:

FORUM HAS BEEN UPGRADED  - if you have trouble logging in, please tap/click "home"  and try again. Hopefully this upgrade addresses recent server issues.  Thank you for your patience. Forum Manager

MESSAGE ABOUT WEBSITE REGISTRATIONS
http://mahoningvalley.info/forum/index.php?topic=8677

Main Menu

Make Health Care Affordable And Accountable

Started by irishbobcat, June 23, 2009, 02:23:06 PM

Previous topic - Next topic

0 Members and 1 Guest are viewing this topic.

irishbobcat

Make Health Care Affordable And Accountable
By Jacob Hacker

June 23, 2009 - 12:08pm ET


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------



This is excerpted from written testimony submitted to the House Education and Labor Committee, one of three House committees jointly writing health care reform legislation, on June 23.


--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
For national health care reform to succeed, it must create accountability in American health insurance, expand coverage while making it more affordable for workers and their families, and adequately fund our health care priorities while putting in place the preconditions for long-term savings to the federal budget. The draft legislation prepared by this special House of Representatives tri-committee promises enormous progress in meeting all three of these goals.

Both accountability within the insurance market and shared responsibility are necessary to slow the growth in health care costs not just for workers and their families but also for employers, states, and the federal government.

In recent years, the need for comprehensive health reform has become glaringly apparent. Health insurance premiums have skyrocketed, more than doubling from 1999 to 2008, while the scope and generosity of private coverage have plummeted. Not only have the ranks of the uninsured continued to expand, but, in addition, the number of Americans who have insurance yet lack adequate protection against medical costs has increased dramatically. More than half of bankruptcy filings are related to medical care, with the vast majority of medical bankruptcies involving households that have insurance coverage. Employers, workers, states and localities, and the federal government—all have seen their budgets under siege because of runaway health care costs and all require long-term relief.

Amid the crisis, there has emerged a growing recognition not just of the need for action but also of the virtues of a public-private "hybrid" approach to health reform. The approach to reform embodied in the tri-committee draft legislation is such a model—a model that builds on the best elements of the present system: large group plans in the public and private sectors. By lowering the cost of care and requiring that all firms eventually contribute to the cost of coverage, the legislation would encourage employers to continue to provide health insurance. At the same time, it would put in place a new means—the so-called health insurance exchange—of allowing Americans without access to secure workplace coverage to choose among insurance plans that provide strong guarantees of quality affordable coverage over time.

An essential feature of this new framework for obtaining group coverage is "public plan choice," the creation of a new public plan modeled after Medicare that would be available to Americans younger than 65 who lack good employment-based coverage. Public plan choice is not by any stretch of the imagination "Medicare for all." Rather, it simply creates a public health insurance plan with incentives to focus on value and innovation that competes on a level playing field with private insurers within the new insurance exchange. Private employment-based coverage would continue, and workers without such coverage would be able to choose from a menu of options that includes a range of private insurance plans as well as the new public health insurance plan.

Moreover, this new public health insurance plan should be—and is, in the draft legislation—self-supporting after initial setup costs are financed (that is, it should be financed by the same sources as any other plan within the exchange, notably, individual premiums, employer contributions, and income-related subsidies). It should also be—and is—subject to the same rules as the private plans and be separate from the national exchange, so the referee (the exchange) does not have a player (the plan) in the game.

This idea is overwhelmingly popular. In a recent poll conducted by the New York Times and CBS News, 72 percent of those questioned supported a government-administered insurance plan that would compete with private insurance. The support for a public plan came from Republicans and Democrats alike. Half of those who identified as Republicans said they would support a public plan, along with three-quarters of independents and nine out of ten Democrats.

Choice, Accountability, and "Healthy Competition"
The aim of public plan choice is healthy competition—that is, competition to make Americans better cared for and more secure. Such competition requires not an endless array of choices, but rather a reasonable number of meaningfully different choices. In much of the country today, health insurance competition is remarkably limited. Most metropolitan areas have no more than a few dominant insurers in control of the market. And these companies are often unable or unwilling to rein in health care costs. It is often in their interest to pay higher rates to key doctors and hospitals because they can pass on these costs to individuals and employers. In the process, they make it difficult for weaker insurers to build competitive provider networks and bring costs down. Even the largest insurers are hard-pressed to enter established markets.

Because the hospital market has grown increasingly concentrated, moreover, providers wield considerable power of their own to drive up the rates they receive from insurers and restrict competition. In areas where hospital market concentration has grown the most, hospital prices and profitability are very high, yet service and quality of care is no better than in other areas, the evidence suggests. As John Holahan and Linda Blumberg of the Urban Institute explain, "Dominant insurers do not seem to use their market power to drive hard bargains with providers . . . . Competition in insurance markets is often about getting the lowest risk enrollees as opposed to competing on price and the efficient delivery of care."

A public health insurance plan would provide greater competition for insurers and providers and greater choice for Americans. Indeed, a key reason for public plan choice is that public health insurance offers a set of valued features that private plans are generally unable or unwilling to provide. Stability, wide pooling of risks, transparency, affordability of premiums, broad provider access, the capacity to collect and use patient information on a large scale to improve care—these are all hallmarks of public health insurance that private plans have inherent difficulties providing. On the other hand, private plans are generally more flexible and more capable of building integrated provider networks, and they have at times moved into new areas of care management in advance of the public sector.

In short, public and private plans have unique strengths, and both should have an important role in a reformed system. Public plan choice simply means that all Americans without good workplace coverage, not just the elderly or the poor, should have access to the distinctive strengths of a public health insurance plan, as well as the strengths of private plans. Such healthy competition has long been the stated rationale for encouraging Medicare to include private plans alongside the public program. The argument for a competitive partnership between public insurance and private plans applies at least as strongly to nonelderly Americans as it does to those in Medicare.

Healthy competition is about accountability. If public and private plans are competing on fair and equal terms, the choice of enrollees between the two will place a crucial check on each. If the public plan becomes too rigid, more Americans will opt for private plans. If private plans engage in practices that obstruct access to needed care and undermine health security, then the public plan will offer a release valve. New rules for private insurance could go some way toward encouraging private plans to focus on providing value. But without a public plan as a benchmark, backup, and check on private plans, key problems in the insurance market will remain.

Public Plan Choice is Essential to Cost Control
Perhaps the most pressing of these problems is skyrocketing costs. Public health insurance has much lower administrative expenses than private plans, it obtains larger volume discounts because of its broad reach, and it does not have to earn profits as many private plans do. Furthermore, experience suggests that these lower costs are accompanied by a superior ability to control spending over time.

Medicare has a better track record than private health plans in controlling costs while maintaining broad access to care, especially over the last fifteen years. By way of illustration, between 1997 and 2006, health spending per enrollee (for comparable benefits) grew at 4.6 percent a year under Medicare, compared with 7.3 percent a year under private health insurance.

Over the last generation, public insurance has pioneered new payment and quality-improvement methods that have frequently set the standard for private plans. More important, it has the potential to carry out these vital tasks much more effectively in the future, using information technology, large databases of practices and outcomes, and new payment approaches and care-coordination strategies. Indeed, a new public plan could spearhead improvement of existing public programs as well as private plans.

To be sure, there are reasonable concerns about how a new public plan will use its bargaining power—concerns reflected in current proposals for state-based public plans, consumer cooperatives established by the states, or even private insurers under public contract. Yet a watered-down public plan or a private alternative to a public plan would not serve the three vital functions of a competing public health insurance plan—to be a "benchmark" for private plans, a "backup" to allow consumers access to a good plan with broad access to providers in all parts of the country, and to serve as a cost-control "backstop." Consumer cooperatives, for example, will be extremely difficult to create and are unlikely to serve as a backup in most of the nation. They will also lack the ability to be a cost-control backstop, much less a benchmark for private plans, because they will not have the reach or authority to implement innovative delivery and payment reforms.

In sum, public plan choice is essential to set a standard against which private plans must compete. Without a public plan competing with private plans, we will continue to lack strong mechanisms to rein in costs and drive value down the road.



--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Jacob S. Hacker is a professor of political science at the University of California, Berkeley
and co-director of the Center on Health Economic & Family Security at the UC Berkeley School of Law.